Saturday, March 3, 2018

Authoritarianism 2 of 2

Continued from Authoritarianism, Affective Polarization, and Economic Ideology (with commentary) 1 of 2

Table 1. Human Capital and Authoritarianism

B
SE
Note. 2016 ANES. DV = Authoritarianism. All variables are coded from zero to one. Entries were obtained using the “survey” package in R, taking into account survey design characteristics according to the recommendations in the 2016 ANES User's Guide.
Intercept
.79
.03
Age
.16
.02
Male
.00
.01
Black
.08
.02
Hispanic
.06
.02
Married
.03
.01
Number of kids
.03
.02
Income
−.06
.03
Unemployed
−.01
.03
South
.06
.01
Education
−.23
.02
Verbal ability
−.33
.03
1 - (Residual dev./Null dev.)
.20
N
3356

What are the implications of this for the relationship of human capital to economic ideology? Based on self-interest theories, we would expect human capital to be associated with reduced demand for redistribution, social insurance, and market regulation. First, individuals with more capital are expected to be more productive, on average, and thus to accumulate greater wealth over the lifespan. In turn, they should be less supportive of progressive taxation and redistribution from rich to poor (Meltzer & Richard, 1981; Stegmueller, 2013). Second, abilities and skills that are portable across occupations and industries provide a form of economic security, because they increase one's adaptability to changing labor-market conditions. For example, individuals with higher levels of cognitive ability may be able to learn new job-specific tasks more easily. Similarly, individuals with higher education may have generalizable skills sets, such as the ability to express themselves clearly in writing, that will be useful in a wide variety of applications. Individuals with highly specific skills, by contrast, are more tied to a specific job or industry and are thus more exposed to economic risks, such as those associated with technological change and automation (Iversen, 2005). In turn, high levels of human capital should be associated with less demand for redistribution, social insurance, and regulation (Iversen, 2005; Iversen & Soskice, 2001; Stegmueller, 2011).

Finally, the United States has a comparative advantage globally with respect to human capital and high-skilled labor. This means that U.S. workers with capital benefit from integration into global markets, while those with low levels of human capital will expect lower wages and job security, on average. In turn, human capital should be associated with less support for government regulation of trade and markets (Scheve & Slaughter, 2001, 2006). In general, then, a self-interest approach suggests that human capital will be associated with economic conservatism.

Other research agrees with this hypothesis but highlights an alternative mechanism. Work by Caplan (2001, 2002, 2007; Caplan & Miller, 2010) shows that noneconomists are more skeptical of free trade and markets than economists, and this cannot be explained solely in terms of differences in ideology, partisanship, or income. However, both cognitive ability and education increase the extent to which people “think like economists.” In turn, these variables should promote free market ideology at the margin.

The results presented in this article, however, suggest that political engagement may reshape how indicators of human capital relate to economic values and policy preferences. If human capital determines (or is at least related to) authoritarianism, and if politically engaged citizens seek out information from elite actors who share their traits and cultural worldview, then the relationship of human capital to economic ideology should reverse direction as a function of engagement, just like authoritarianism in Figure 3. At low levels of engagement, we may see the standard prediction from self-interest theories and Caplan's work, with low human-capital citizens more liberal than their high-capital counterparts. But as engagement increases, low-capital citizens should become increasingly conservative, and high-capital citizens should become increasingly liberal. Moreover, these changes should be explained, to a substantial extent at least, by differences in authoritarianism.

To examine this possibility, I estimated models like those underpinning Figure 3, but I substituted interactions of education and verbal ability with engagement for the interactions of authoritarianism with engagement. For these models, I again exclude African-American identifiers.26 The regression estimates are shown in the appendix, and I plot the key quantities in Figure 6. Overall, I find interactions of education and verbal ability with engagement qualitatively like those for authoritarianism. The constituent terms for education are positive in both models, and for verbal ability in the values model, which implies that economic conservatism increases as human capital increases among the politically unengaged. However, the interactions are large and negative, which indicates that the relationship of human capital to economic ideology flips sign as engagement increases. These coefficients are statistically significant for education in both models, but are not significant for verbal ability, though the interaction terms are quite large for ability in both cases.27 As the two variables are substantially correlated (r = .39), their effects likely overlap to some degree.28

Figure 6.
Economic preferences and human capital. Data is from the 2016 ANES.

The top panel of Figure 6 shows the key estimates for economic policy, and the bottom panel shows the same for limited government values. The y-axes represent increasingly conservative views. The x-axes represent increasing levels of political engagement (ranging from its 5th to 95th percentile). I plot predicted values of conservatism for two types of respondents: those with relatively low levels of human capital and those with relatively high levels of human capital. I define “low” as individuals with no more than a high school degree or equivalent who score at the 25th percentile of verbal ability. I define “high” as individuals with a graduate degree who score at the 75th percentile of verbal ability. For economic policy, for individuals with low levels of human capital, a shift in political engagement from low to high is associated with an increase in conservatism of one-third of one standard deviation.29 At high levels of human capital, the same change in engagement is associated with a decline in conservatism of .50 standard deviations. In other words, individuals with relatively low education and verbal ability become more right-wing on economic issues as engagement increases, while those with high levels of these indicators become more left-wing. The results are similar for limited government values. Here, the respective changes are .36 and −.61 points on the 4-point scale, respectively. Moreover, this pattern implies a reversal of the sign of the relationship between human capital and economic preferences across engagement. As seen in the figure, at low levels of engagement, human capital is positively associated with economic conservatism, but at high levels of engagement, human capital is negatively associated with conservatism. These results are surprising from a self-interest perspective: Citizens are lesslikely to pursue their prima facie economic interests as political sophistication increases (Johnston et al., 2017, Chap. 7). But this pattern is exactly what we should expect if human capital is associated with authoritarianism, and engaged citizens are seeking out information on economic issues from elites who share their traits and cultural worldview.

It is difficult to formally test the degree to which the human-capital interaction is mediated by authoritarianism, but we can do a rough test by adding the authoritarianism interaction to each model. Mediation by authoritarianism implies that the interactions with human capital should be substantially reduced in magnitude, and likely driven to insignificance. As shown in Table A3 in the appendix, this is indeed the case. Thus, the data are at least consistent with a model in which education and verbal ability (or some antecedent factor causing both) shape authoritarianism, and authoritarianism shapes economic preferences in interaction with political engagement. However, it is possible that there is an excluded mediator correlated with authoritarianism that better explains these results.

Conclusions

Previous research argues that affective polarization is rooted in the rise of elite partisan divisions over issues that tap into authoritarianism, such as sexuality, gender, law and order, immigration, and terrorism (Hetherington & Weiler, 2009). Yet, recent work shows that Republicans and Democrats are now sorted and sharply divided on economic issues as well (Webster & Abramowitz, 2017), and some of the most heated debates of recent years concern seemingly technical questions, such as those surrounding health insurance reform. In the present article, I have shown that these competing perspectives may be reconciled to some degree, and authoritarianism (and related personality factors) may be part of the explanation for the link between polarization on size-of-government issues and out-party dislike (Webster & Abramowitz, 2017). The authoritarian divide has infused economic debates in the United States because engaged citizens seek out, trust, and assimilate information about economic policy from elites who share their traits and cultural worldview. Consistent with this theory, among the politically engaged, child-rearing values are very strongly associated with both party affect and economic conservatism, trumping income and other common predictors of economic ideology in terms of explanatory value. In two experimental studies, I also provided evidence that partisan-ideological and cultural cue-taking is the causal mechanism driving this correlation among engaged citizens.

In principle, politically active citizens could use distinct decision rules in forming preferences across distinct dimensions of policy. For example, authoritarianism might structure information seeking for issues concerning (say) terrorism, but heuristics related to class might structure information-seeking on issues of social welfare and market regulation. I might trust people who exude “toughness” when it comes to thinking about how to deal with ISIS but turn to those who share a class identity when it comes to health insurance reform (e.g., Carnes & Sadin, 2014). This is true, even when—as in the United States—the system effectively forces a choice between candidates of only two parties on Election Day. If dimensions are kept distinct, vote choice becomes a problem of weighing and combining the various policy dimensions per one's priorities. That is, one can maintain the independence of ideological dimensions and then trade off preferences across dimensions when confronting the binary choice at the voting booth.

Yet, this is not how engaged citizens appear to operate. Instead, they seem to have a strong need to reconcile their economic views with the personality and cultural divisions emphasized by Hetherington and Weiler (2009) and others (e.g., Frank, 2004; Haidt, 2012; Jost et al., 2003). This may be due to the depth and emotional intensity of conflicts rooted in these considerations. As argued by Kahan (2015) in his work on climate change opinion, it may be too socially costly to deviate from the economic views of those who share one's traits and cultural values; or, perhaps, too disconcerting to associate oneself with the economic views of opponents who are strongly disliked for these reasons. As partisanship has become increasingly tied to authoritarianism among politically engaged citizens, it may be more difficult than in the past to contemplate agreeing with one's opponents on just about anything (Hetherington & Rudolph, 2015)—even seemingly technical issues like many of those in the economic domain. In this sense, consistent with Webster and Abramowitz (2017), engaged citizens are disagreeing disagreeably on economic issues; but, consistent with Mason (2015b), the root cause of the conflict is only loosely connected to policy content: “We might believe that we are responding to specific policy disputes, but to a very real extent we are also being driven by an automatic, basic need to defend our social group” (p. 58).

These considerations suggest that competing explanations for affective polarization are difficult to disentangle. For example, in a survey experiment, Webster and Abramowitz (2017) find that policy position taking strongly shapes citizens' feelings toward political actors. The implication is that affective polarization is driven by ideology and economic policy preferences. While this interpretation is reasonable, it is important to remember that citizens' economic values and issue opinions are not fully exogenous to the other dimensions that roil partisan conflict, and this fact may shape our interpretations of the treatment effect. If authoritarianism is at the root of economic values and preferences, is negative affect in this experiment driven by policy position taking per se or by what position taking signals about the traits and cultural values of the speaker? The present article suggests the latter interpretation may be reasonable.

The present article also has broader implications for the distribution of opinion on issues of redistribution, social insurance, and market regulation across levels of human capital. Prior work suggests that indicators of human capital should be associated with less support for government intervention in the economy (e.g., Caplan, 2007; Caplan & Miller, 2010; Iversen, 2005; Scheve & Slaughter, 2001). Yet this work fails to consider how human capital may also operate on preferences indirectly via its association with personality traits and cultural orientations. In societies like the United States (Malka et al., 2014), in which parties collapse economic and cultural issues to a single dimension, the tendency of high-capital citizens to identify with the cultural left can distort the expected relationship of capital to free-market conservatism, because citizens receive utility from endorsing policies consistent with their cultural ingroup. This helps to explain the tendency of engaged citizens to support economic policies that seem to work against their narrow economic interests (Johnston et al., 2017, Chap. 7). This is a distinct mechanism by which the “culture wars” can influence economic policy outcomes. Rather than displacing the economic domain as a consideration in vote choice—an idea that is the focus of much previous work (e.g., Ansolabehere, Rodden, & Snyder, 2006; Bartels, 2006; Frank, 2004)—the rise of cultural conflict may change the very bases of economic preferences, tying these to the traits and values that shape citizens' reactions to the symbols of cultural liberalism and conservatism, and thus altering the structure of ideology for politically active citizens.

Correspondence concerning this article should be addressed to Christopher D. Johnston, Box 90204, Durham, NC 27708. E-mail: cdj19@duke.edu

Footnotes
1
The data are from the 2016 American National Election Study (ANES). Relative party affect is defined as the difference in party feeling thermometers. “Politically engaged” is defined as respondents in the top 25% of the distribution of political interest and knowledge (see the appendix for variables used to construct this scale). Authoritarianism is measured with the standard set of four child-rearing items, which are also provided in the appendix.
2
For an in-depth examination of differences across racial and ethnic groups, see Johnston et al. (2017; see also Gerber, Huber, Doherty, Dowling, & Ha, 2010).
3
Tesler's (2012, 2015) work on the spillover of racial attitudes onto healthcare opinion in the Obama era is similar in this respect, as is Kahan and Braman's (2006) conceptualization of cultural cognition. In Tesler's work, racial attitudes become linked to seemingly unrelated issues, because Obama is a persistent prime for racial attitudes, and because citizens use what amounts to an affect heuristic in deciding whom to believe at the elite level. In Kahan and Braman's work, citizens trust elites on factual issues when they share core values related to hierarchy and individualism. Both programs have influenced our thinking about the influence of personality on preference formation (Johnston et al., 2017).
4
See the appendix for the items used to construct the economic policy scale.
5
Throughout the article, I will use the terms “liberal” and “conservative” in the contemporary American sense of support and opposition to government intervention in markets, respectively.
6
Research suggests that cognitive ability is linked to support for markets (Caplan & Miller, 2010). I will further discuss the relevance of this variable in the last empirical section.
7
Significance tests for conditional marginal effects are conducted via simulation from the sampling distribution. A “significant” marginal effect is defined as one for which 95% of the simulated coefficients are on one side of zero.
8
There is no significant interaction between income and engagement when I add the latter to the model. When I remove authoritarianism and its interaction from the model, there is a significant interaction between engagement and income, but engagement reduces the size of income's effect on preferences. That is, the effect of income is strongest for the least engaged citizens. This replicates the pattern reported in Johnston et al. (2017, Chap. 7).
9
Johnston et al. (2017) find support for this “reversal hypothesis” in ANES data from 1992 to 2012. Malka et al. (2014) find support for the same reversal in other political contexts using World Values Survey data.
10
The analysis here differs a bit from that reported in Open versus Closed. First, I examine only non-Black respondents. Second, I specify the regression model in the second experiment in a slightly different way to demonstrate that the results are robust to alternative ways of modeling the engagement interaction.
11
The survey was conducted by YouGov in March of 2011.
12
Conservation versus openness-to-change values have been used in previous work to tap the predisposition to authoritarianism (Feldman, 2003), and the need for closure is closely related to other measures of authoritarianism (RWA, Jost et al., 2003). Scores on the authoritarianism dimension are correlated at .79 with scores on the superordinate factor in these data (Johnston et al. 2017, p. 190).
13
The appendix contains the exact wording for these items.
14
Respondents were assigned to the same condition for each of the four issues, and I combine the four preference items into a single scale (α = .80).
15
When the elite-cues conditions are examined separately, the effect of cues is much larger for partisanship than for ideology. Additional work with a larger sample size is needed to determine if this is a reliable pattern or idiosyncratic to these data.
16
In Figure 4, the x-axis ranges from the 5th percentile of the personality scale (“Low”) to the 95th percentile (“High”).
17
I do not, however, find a reversal at low levels of engagement. This is perhaps due to the smaller sample size and greater overall level of engagement of this study relative to the ANES. There may be too few very unengaged citizens in these samples to detect the reversal. Alternatively, as we discuss in Johnston et al. (2017), the positive effect of authoritarianism among the engaged may simply be stronger and more reliable than the negative effect among the unengaged.
18
The goal here was to increase the generalizability of the study by including distinct types of economic issues.
19
This measure is similar to other recent work on policy choice in the context of candidate position taking (Sniderman & Stiglitz, 2012; Tomz & van Houweling, 2008).
20
Unfortunately, there are relatively few truly unengaged respondents in the CCES sample.
21
See Brandt and Crawford (2016) for an important theoretical and empirical caveat to the cognitive ability to prejudice link. They argue and find that ability is related to prejudice in different ways depending on the target group. Low cognitive ability is associated with prejudice against groups that tend to be associated with the political left, while high cognitive ability is associated with prejudice against groups associated with the political right.
22
See Cor, Haertel, Krosnick, and Malhotra, (2012) for a psychometric critique of the 10-item inventory. The problem highlighted in this article is that the inventory contains insufficient coverage of the latent ability domain. This appears to be true in the 2016 ANES, in that there are no items with very high levels of difficulty. This suggests that the test will not be able to discriminate among respondents with moderately high and very high ability levels (Embretson & Reise, 2000). For the purposes of the present article, however, this should not present a serious problem, as I am interested in the nature of the relationship between ability and preferences, rather than individual-level estimates of ability. If anything, the reduced variation at the high end of ability should result in conservative estimates of the magnitude of the relationship of ability to authoritarianism and economic preferences.
23
For example, as reported in Caplan and Miller (2010, p. 639), past research has found correlations between general intelligence and verbal ability of .70 or higher (e.g., Wolfe, 1980).
24
A simple loess fit of authoritarianism to educational attainment suggests that this relationship is close to linear across the categories of the latter variable.
25
But see Pérez and Hetherington (2014) for a critical treatment of the Black-White gap in authoritarianism.
26
As with the models for authoritarianism, the results are stronger if I consider only non-Hispanic Whites. I report the models for non-Blacks to maximize population coverage and thus to increase the generalizability of the reported results.
27
In non-Hispanic-Whites-only models, the constituent and interaction terms for ability are larger and statistically significant in the values model and increase substantially in absolute magnitude in the policy model.
28
It is also possible that the effects of verbal ability are mediated by education. Consistent with this possibility, the interactions for ability are significant when I remove education from the models. It is, however, impossible to determine the causal sequence using these data.
29
All marginal effects reported in this section are statistically significant.



References

·          Abramowitz, A. I. (2010). The disappearing center: Engaged citizens, polarization, and American democracyNew Haven, CT: Yale University Press.
·          Abramowitz, A. I., & Saunders, K. (1998). Ideological realignment in the U.S. electorateJournal of Politics60(3), 634652.
o                               CrossRef
·          Abramowitz, A. I., & Saunders, K. (2005). Why Can't we all just get along? The reality of a polarized AmericaThe Forum3(2), 122.
o                               CrossRef
·          Abramowitz, A. I., & Webster, S. (2016). The rise of negative partisanship and the nationalization of U.S. elections in the 21st centuryElectoral Studies411222.
o                               CrossRef
·          Adorno, T. W.Frenkel-Brunswik, E.Levinson, D. J., & Sanford, R. N. (1950). The Authoritarian personalityNew York, NY: Harper and Row.
·          Altemeyer, B. (1981). Right-wing authoritarianismManitoba, Canada: University of Manitoba Press.
·          Altemeyer, B. (1988). Enemies of freedom: Understanding right-wing authoritarianismHoboken, NJ: Jossey-Bass.
·          Ansolabehere, S.Rodden, J., & Snyder, J. M. (2008). The strength of issues: Using multiple measures to gauge preference stability, ideological constraint, and issue votingAmerican Political Science Review102(2), 215232.
o                               CrossRef
·          Bafumi, J., & Shapiro, R. Y. (2009). A new partisan voterJournal of Politics71(1), 124.
o                               CrossRef
·          Bartels, L. M. (2006). What's the matter with what's the matter with Kansas? Quarterly Journal of Political Science1201226.
o                               CrossRef
·          Brandt, M. J., & Crawford, J. T. (2016). Answering unresolved questions about the relationship between cognitive ability and prejudiceSocial Psychological and Personality Science7(8), 884892.
o                               CrossRef
·          Caplan, B. (2001). What makes people think like economists? Evidence on economic cognition from the “Survey of Americans and economists on the economy.” Journal of Law and Economics44(2), 395426.
o                               CrossRef
·          Caplan, B. (2002). Systematically biased beliefs about economics: Robust evidence of judgmental anomalies from the “Survey of Americans and economists on the economy.” Economic Journal112433458.
o                               CrossRef
·          Caplan, B. (2007). The myth of the American voter: Why democracies choose bad policiesPrinceton, NJ: Princeton University Press.
·          Caplan, B., & Miller, S. C. (2010). Intelligence makes people think like economists: Evidence from the General Social SurveyIntelligence38(6), 636647.
o                               CrossRef
·          Caprara, G. V., & Zimbardo, P. G. (2004). Personalizing politics: A congruency model of political preferenceAmerican Psychologist59(7), 581594.
o                               CrossRef | 
o                               PubMed
·          Carmines, E. G., & Stimson, J. A. (1980). The two faces of issue votingAmerican Political Science Review74(1), 7891.
o                               CrossRef
·          Carnes, N., & Sadin, M. L. (2015). The “mill worker's son” heuristic: How voters perceive politicians from working-class families—and how they really behave in officeJournal of Politics77(1), 285298.
o                               CrossRef
·          Cizmar, A. M.Layman, G. C.McTague, J.Pearson-Merkowitz, S., & Spivey, M. (2014). Authoritarianism and American political behavior from 1952 to 2008Political Research Quarterly67(1), 7183.
o                               CrossRef
·          Cor, M. K.Haertel, E.Krosnick, J. A., & Malhotra, N. (2012). Improving ability measurement in surveys by following the principles of IRT: The Wordsum vocabulary test in the General Social SurveySocial Science Research41(5), 10031016.
o                               CrossRef | 
o                               PubMed
·          Duckitt, J. (2001). A dual-process cognitive-motivational theory of ideology and prejudiceAdvances in Experimental Social Psychology3341114.
o                               CrossRef
·          Embretson, S. E., & Reise, S. P. (2000). Item response theory for psychologistsMahwah, NJ: Erlbaum.
·          Federico, C. M., & Malka, A. (2018). The contingent, contextual nature of the relationship between needs for security and certainty and political preferences: Evidence and implicationsAdvances in Political Psychology39. doi: 10.1111/pops.12477
o                               CrossRef
·          Federico, C. M., & Tagar, M. R. (2014). Zeroing in on the right: Education and the partisan expression of authoritarianism in the United StatesPolitical Behavior36(3), 581603.
o                               CrossRef
·          Feldman, S. (2003). Enforcing social conformity: A theory of authoritarianismPolitical Psychology24(1), 4174.
o                               CrossRef
·          Feldman, S., & Johnston, C. (2014). Understanding the determinants of political ideology: Implications of structural complexityPolitical Psychology35(3), 337358.
o                               CrossRef
·          Feldman, S., & Stenner, K. (1997). Perceived threat and authoritarianismPolitical Psychology18(4), 741770.
o                               CrossRef
·          Frank, T. (2004). What's the matter with Kansas? How conservatives won the heart of AmericaNew York, NY: Henry Holt and Company.
·          Gerber, A. S.Huber, G. A.Doherty, D.Dowling, C. M., & Ha, S. E. (2010). Personality and political attitudes: Relationships across issue domains and political contextsAmerican Political Science Review104(1), 111133.
o                               CrossRef
·          Haidt, J. (2012). The righteous mind: Why good people are divided by politics and religionNew York, NY: Pantheon Books.
·          Heider, F. (1958). The psychology of interpersonal relationsHillsdale, NJ: Erlbaum.
o                               CrossRef
·          Hetherington, M. J., & Rudolph, T. J. (2015). Why Washington won't workChicago, IL: University of Chicago Press.
o                               CrossRef
·          Hetherington, M., & Suhay, E. (2011). Authoritarianism, threat, and Americans' support for the war on terrorAmerican Journal of Political Science55(3), 546560.
o                               CrossRef
·          Hetherington, M. J., & Weiler, J. D. (2009). Authoritarianism and polarization in American politicsNew York, NY: Cambridge University Press.
o                               CrossRef
·          Hodson, G., & Busseri, M. A. (2012). Bright minds and dark attitudes: Lower cognitive ability predicts greater prejudice through right-wing ideology and low intergroup ContactPsychological Science23(2), 187195.
o                               CrossRef | 
o                               PubMed
·          Huddy, L.Mason, L., & Aarøe, L. (2015). Expressive partisanship: Campaign involvement, political emotion, and partisan identityAmerican Political Science Review109(1), 117.
o                               CrossRef
·          Iversen, T. (2005). Capitalism, democracy, and welfareNew York, NY: Cambridge University Press.
o                               CrossRef
·          Iversen, T., & Soskice, D. (2001). An asset theory of social policy preferencesAmerican Political Science Review95(4), 875894.
·          Iyengar, S.Sood, G., & Lelkes, Y. (2012). Affect, not ideology a social identity perspective on polarizationPublic Opinion Quarterly76(3), 405431.
o                               CrossRef
·          Iyengar, S., & Westwood, S. J. (2014). Fear and loathing across party lines: New evidence on group polarizationAmerican Journal of Political Science59(3), 690707.
o                               CrossRef
·          Johnston, C. D.Lavine, H. G., & Federico, C. M. (2017). Open versus closed: Personality, identity, and the politics of redistributionNew York, NY: Cambridge University Press.
o                               CrossRef
·          Johnston, C. D., & Wronski, J. (2015). Personality dispositions and political preferences across hard and easy issuesPolitical Psychology36(1), 3553.
o                               CrossRef | 
o                               PubMed
·          Jost, J. T.Glaser, J.Kruglanski, A. W., & Sulloway, F. J. (2003). Political conservatism as motivated social cognitionPsychological Bulletin129(3), 339375.
o                               CrossRef | 
o                               PubMed
·          Kahan, D. M. (2015). Climate-science communication and the measurement problemAdvances in Political Psychology36143.
o                               CrossRef
·          Kahan, D. M., & Braman, D. (2006). Cultural cognition and public policyYale Law & Policy Review24(1), 149172.
·          Kan, K.-J.Wicherts, J. M.Dolan, C. V., & van der Maas, H. L. J. (2013). On the nature and nurture of intelligence and specific cognitive abilities: The more heritable, the more culture dependentPsychological Science24(12), 24202428.
o                               CrossRef | 
o                               PubMed
·          Kruglanski, A. W.Pierro, A.Mannetti, L., & De Grada, E. (2006). Groups as epistemic providers: Need for closure and the unfolding of group-centrismPsychological Review113(1), 84100.
o                               CrossRef | 
o                               PubMed
·          Kruglanski, A. W., & Webster, D. M. (1996). Motivated closing of the mind: “Seizing” and “freezing.” Psychological Review103(2), 263283.
o                               CrossRef | 
o                               PubMed | 
o                               CAS
·          Lavine, H.Lodge, M.Polichak, J., & Taber, J. C. (2002). Explicating the black box through experimentation: Studies of authoritarianism and threatPolitical Analysis10(4), 343361.
o                               CrossRef
·          Lupia, A., & McCubbins, M. D. (1998). The democratic dilemma: Can citizens learn what they need to knowNew York, NY: Cambridge University Press.
·          Malka, A.Soto, C. J.Inzlicht, M., & Lelkes, Y. (2014). Do needs for security and certainty predict cultural and economic conservatism? A cross-national analysisJournal of Personality and Social Psychology106(6), 10311051.
o                               CrossRef | 
o                               PubMed
·          Mason, L. (2015a). “I disrespectfully agree”: The differential effects of partisan sorting on social and issue polarizationAmerican Journal of Political Science59(1), 128145.
o                               CrossRef
·          Mason, L. (2015b). Party polarization is making us more prejudiced. In D. J. Hopkins & J. Sides (Eds.), Political polarization in American politics (pp. 5560). New York, NY: Bloomsbury.
·          Mason, L. (2016). A cross-cutting calm: How social sorting drives affective polarizationPublic Opinion Quarterly80(1), 351377.
o                               CrossRef
·          Meltzer, A. H., & Richard, S. F. (1981). A rational theory of the size of governmentJournal of Political Economy89(5), 914927.
o                               CrossRef
·          Onraet, E.Van Hiel, A.Dhont, K.Hodson, G.Schittekatte, M., & De Pauw, S. (2015). The association of cognitive ability with right-wing ideological attitudes and prejudice: A meta-analytic reviewEuropean Journal of Personality29599621.
o                               CrossRef
·          Oxley, D. R.Smith, K. B.Alford, J. R.Hibbing, M. V.Miller, J. L.Scalora, M.Hatemi, P. K., & Hibbing, J. R. (2008). Political attitudes vary with physiological traitsScience32116671670.
o                               CrossRef | 
o                               PubMed | 
o                               CAS | 
o                               ADS
·          Pérez, E. O., & Hetherington, M. J. (2014). Authoritarianism in Black and White: Testing the cross-racial validity of the child rearing scalePolitical Analysis22(3), 398412.
o                               CrossRef
·          Rogowski, J. C., & Sutherland, J. L. (2016). How ideology fuels affective polarizationPolitical Behavior38(2), 485508.
o                               CrossRef
·          Scheve, K. F., & Slaughter, M. J. (2001). What determines individual trade-policy preferences? Journal of International Economics54(2), 267292.
o                               CrossRef
·          Scheve, K. F., & Slaughter, M. J. (2006). Public opinion, international economic integration, and the welfare state. In D. R. CameronG. Ranis, & A. Zinn (Eds.), Globalization and self-determination: Is the nation-state under siege? (pp. 5194). New York, NY: Routledge.
·          Schwartz, S. H. (1992). Universals in the content and structure of values: Theoretical advances and empirical tests in 20 countriesAdvances in Experimental Social Psychology25(1), 165.
·          Sinclair, B. (2012). The social citizen: Peer networks and political behaviorChicago, IL: University of Chicago Press.
o                               CrossRef
·          Sniderman, P. M., & Stiglitz, E. H. (2012). The reputational premium: A theory of party identification and policy reasoningPrinceton, NJ: Princeton University Press.
·          Stegmueller, D. (2011). Apples and oranges? The problem of equivalence in comparative researchPolitical Analysis19(4), 471487.
o                               CrossRef
·          Stegmueller, D. (2013). The dynamics of income expectations and redistribution preferences. Presented at the annual meeting of the American Political Science Association, Chicago, IL.
·          Stenner, K. (2005). The authoritarian dynamicNew York, NY: Cambridge University Press.
o                               CrossRef
·          Tesler, M. (2012). The spillover of racialization into health care: How President Obama polarized public opinion by racial attitudes and raceAmerican Journal of Political Science 56(3), 690704.
o                               CrossRef
·          Tesler, M. (2015). Priming predispositions and changing policy positions: An account of when mass opinion is primed or changedAmerican Journal of Political Science59(4), 806824.
o                               CrossRef
·          Thorndike, R. L. (1942). Two screening tests of verbal intelligenceJournal of Applied Psychology26(2), 128135.
o                               CrossRef
·          Tomz, M., & Van Houweling, R. P. (2008). Candidate positioning and voter choiceAmerican Political Science Review102(3), 303318.
o                               CrossRef
·          Webster, S. W., & Abramowitz, A. I. (2017). The ideological foundations of affective polarization in the U.S. electorateAmerican Politics Research.doi:10.1177%2F1532673X17703132.
o                               CrossRef
·          Wechsler, D. (1958). The measurement and appraisal of adult intelligenceBaltimore, MD: Williams and Wilkens.
o                               CrossRef
·          Wolfe, L. M. (1980). The enduring effects of educationSociology of Education53(2), 104114.
o                               CrossRef



No comments:

Post a Comment